In the Paris Agreement, adopted in 2015, countries agreed to hold global mean temperature rise to well-below-2°C while pursuing to limit it to 1.5°C. Since then, the scientific community has focussed its efforts on understanding what it would take for the world to meet this target1. Modelling since Paris has looked at requirements to meet the most stringent 1.5°C ambition2, quantification of the required transformations3,4, and of the consequences of living in a 2°C rather than a 1.5°C world5. Initial climate pledges made in the context of the Paris negotiations were soon found inadequate6, but, despite the slower-than-necessary pace7,8, countries have kept ramping up their climate action and ambition since. Several studies have so far quantified the actual impact of international policy efforts9–11 and established that loosely defined business-as-usual scenarios missing that impact started making less sense12,13, thereby increasing the pressure for a better and a more realistic analysis of where the world is headed based on current policies and pledges14. A growing body of literature15–17, thus, shed light on what policies currently in place as well as official 2030 Nationally Determined Contributions (NDCs) would yield, establishing that they are inadequate to limit warming to 2°C18,19.
Although the critical climate talks of the 26th Conference of the Parties (COP26)—a milestone for ratcheting ambition—were delayed by a year due to COVID-19, parties followed up on their commitments; by the time COP26 was completed in Glasgow in November 2021, more than 120 countries had upgraded their 2030 targets20 and major emitters representing over 70% of the world’s CO2 emissions had announced and/or adopted net-zero commitments21. A handful of studies attempted to quickly assess the outcome of these new promises22–26, showing that—if fully implemented—global climate ambition could hold the rise in global temperatures to just-below-2°C by the end of the century. More efforts to comprehend the effect of the new generation of NDCs and long-term targets (LTTs) followed27,28. Nonetheless, each of these studies was based on a single model and, despite stagnation of new such bold promises in 2022 largely due to the current energy crisis29, a multi-model assessment of global climate pledges remains critical. Our study contributes to this research gap, aiming to enhance the robustness and confidence in our knowledge of the possible global warming outcomes, by exploiting a diverse ensemble of models.
Model diversity also implies a plurality of modelling paradigms, theories, solution mechanisms, and thus of pathways that each model yields30. Given the pursuit of and political commitment to 1.5°C—which was further strengthened in the Glasgow Climate Pact1—and the ambition reflected in announced net-zero pledges, special emphasis is increasingly placed on thresholds or boundaries that modelled pathways must stay within to be considered feasible31. According to the 6th Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change (IPCC AR6), feasibility refers to the potential for a mitigation (or adaptation) option to be implemented, based on a diversity of context-dependent factors32—including institutional, financial, and political factors33–35. Conversely, from a modelling perspective, feasibility refers to quantifiable geophysical, environmental-ecological, technological, economic, and even sociocultural factors36. Feasibility assessments hitherto referred to challenges at the global level37,38 and/or have been used to explicitly assess 1.5°C-compliant pathways39, without touching upon regional feasibility concerns of decarbonisation pathways that are required to achieve announced pledges. Our study builds on and expands the multidimensional feasibility assessment framework established by Brutschin et al. (2021)37, further disaggregating it at the regional level, to assess to what extent and from which perspective countries’ policy targets, NDCs, and LTTs are feasible.
Defining Scenarios And Feasibility Indicators
Quantifying gaps requires quantifying where the world is headed given current levels of climate action and ambition. We use three scenarios, each corresponding to a different level of climate action or stated ambition (Fig. 1): (1) a scenario with current emission reduction policies until 2030 with a post-2030 extrapolation maintaining 2020–2030 emission intensity tendencies (EI), (2) a scenario with current NDC targets for 2030 with the same EI extrapolation, and (3) a scenario with NDC targets until 2030 followed by LTTs. All policies and targets submitted or announced by June 2022 are included in these scenarios.
Comparing the scenario outcomes allows us to subdivide the climate action gap, that is, the difference between the emission reductions and related temperature outcomes that can be expected with the current set of policies in all countries, with the announced Paris goal of pursuing to keep global temperature increase below 1.5°C. The difference in 2100 or peak temperature (depending on whether a peak is reached in the 21st century) of current policies and that of 2030 NDCs, both extended by EI trends, is termed the implementation gap. The temperature difference between the 2030 NDCs extended by EI trends, and the 2030 NDCs followed by LTTs (where stated) is termed the “long-term ratchet gap”, referring to the pace in which post-2030 action must be accelerated relative to pre-2030 action to deliver on long-term targets. The difference between the peak temperature of 2030 NDCs followed by available LTTs and the 1.5°C target is termed the “ambition gap”.
Apart from the climate action gap, this study looks into the feasibility of pathways based on country-specific policies and announced emission reduction targets. Feasibility concerns are measured by comparing specific model outcomes with threshold values found in the literature (see Methods). A total of 10 different feasibility indicators are estimated, which can be divided into three categories: (a) socioeconomic feasibility concerns related with the cost burden of mitigation policies, (b) technology scale-up feasibility concerns related with the velocity at which clean technologies can replace existing technologies in place, and (c) physical feasibility constraints related with the physical potentials for bioenergy production and carbon storage. Feasibility concerns are measured by model region and for each 10-year time-step (between 2020 and 2050) to illustrate “where” and “when” we find the largest bottlenecks to climate change mitigation.
Global Action Gap
We focus on global CO2 emissions from energy and industrial processes to 2050 as all our IAMs represent these emissions sources as a minimum. Taking into account all relevant national and regional energy and climate policies on top of socio- and techno-economic baseline assumptions, we find that emissions will stabilise or start declining in the current decade, reaching 33–38 Gt by 2030 (Fig. 2). If policy effort is sufficiently strengthened to reach stated NDC emission targets, we find across models that emissions are reduced towards 2030, reaching 30–33 Gt. If all countries continue their declining trend in emission intensity of GDP beyond 2030, global emissions will achieve levels of around 24–30 Gt and 19–23 by 2050—for current policies and NDCs, respectively. However, if countries accelerate action post-2030 to meet their stated long-term emission targets, we find 2050 emissions in the range of 10–13 Gt.
The model spread is largest for current policies, since models run largely in forecasting mode, simulating the impact of policies relative to a model-dependent no-policy baseline. Despite many of the model input assumptions being harmonised to reduce unwanted response heterogeneity (see SI), no-policy baselines tend to differ strongly, driven by inherent model characteristics as well as remaining unharmonised inputs18. Therefore, despite the converging effect of modelling a common set of current energy and climate policies, model variation still tends to be large in such exercises14,40 (Table 1). The model spread for emissions significantly decreases when emission targets from NDCs and LTTs are used as absolute constraints to the models. The remaining emission spread can be explained by a mix of factors, such as model regions overperforming their stated targets, differences in regional aggregation, and the CO2 vs non-CO2 share in emission reductions. While total emissions outcomes between models converge when applying constraints, the distribution of emissions over the different sectors diverge between the models, reflecting the heterogeneity of mitigation pathways preferred by each model (see Extended Fig. 1).
Table 1
Model key characteristics
| GCAM-PR | GEMINI-E3 | MUSE | TIAM-Grantham |
Model type | Partial equilibrium | General equilibrium | Agent-based energy-system | Partial equilibrium |
Solution dynamic | Recursive-dynamic | Recursive-dynamic | Recursive-dynamic | Inter-temporal optimisation (perfect foresight) |
Technology choice | Logit choice | Nested CES function | xx | Winner takes all |
GHG emission coverage (reported) | Fossil CO2, CH4, N2O, Land-use CO2, F-gases, | Fossil CO2, CH4, N2O, F-gases | Fossil CO2 | Fossil CO2 |
Model regions | 32 | 11 | 20 | 15 |
Time horizon | 2100 | 2050 | 2100 | 2100 |
Unconstrained baseline CO2 1 | High | High | Low | Medium |
Impact of current policies 1 | Medium | High | Low | High |
Major feasibility concerns with LTTs2: | | | | |
Timing and indicator | Long-term bioenergy and carbon storage | Long-term energy demand reduction | Near and long-term carbon pricing | Near term technology scale-up |
Region(s) | India, Japan | USA | EU, Japan | EU, India, Japan |
Explanation based on model structure | Due to the endogenous representation of the land sector, no hard limits are set to bioenergy supply. High energy prices stimulate bio-energy output from land beyond sustainable limits. | As a general equilibrium model, the entire economy is simulated, including economic feedbacks to end-use sectors. High energy prices therefore lead to relatively high demand reduction | Due to high inertia by modelled agents and technology stickiness, high carbon prices are required to switch to low carbon technologies and/or reduce demand. | As an inter-temporal perfect foresight model, agents have perfect foresight towards the future, driving the near-term investment in renewable technologies. |
1 For baseline CO2, High > 40 GtCO2, low < 30 GtCO2, Medium = 30–40 GtCO2 by 2050. For impact from current policies, High > 6 GtCO2, Low < 3 GtCO2, Medium = 3–6 GtCO2 reduction to baseline in 2030. 2 Major feasibility concerns are identified separately per model, and not by comparing feasibility concerns between the different models. |
After harmonising the emission data, infilling missing species, and running the emission outcomes through the simple climate model FaIR (see Methods), we find that current ambition levels signalled through implemented energy and climate policies will increase global temperatures to 2.1–2.4°C above pre-industrial levels by 2100, depending on the model (1.9–2.7°C when including climate uncertainty at the 25–75% interval), while ambitions levels stated in present NDCs slightly limit this temperature increase to 2.0-2.2°C (1.7–2.5 for 25–75% interval). In both cases, warming will continue after 2100, as global CO2 emissions have not yet reached net-zero levels. If countries also comply with their stated LTTs after meeting their current NDC pledges in 2030, temperature increase will be further limited and stabilise around 1.7–1.8°C (1.5–2.0°C for 25–75% interval), which is arguably in line with a “well-below 2°C” future41. Depending on the model applied, this translates to an implementation gap leading to 0.1–0.4°C additional warming on the one hand, and a long-term ratchet gap equivalent to another 0.2–0.5°C of warming on the other. The remaining global ambition gap compared to the Paris target of keeping global temperature increase to 1.5°Cwould be around 0.2–0.3°C for all models. For 3 out of 4 models (GEMINI, MUSE and TIAM), the long-term ratchet gap contributes most to the entire climate action gap. This confirms previous assessments showing that mitigation in current NDCs is not aligned with long-term targets for most countries24,27. For GCAM, the implementation gap contributes most to the entire gap, instead.
Disaggregating the emission results for the six largest emitters (Fig. 4) shows where the different gaps are more relevant. The implementation gap is measured to be largest (in relative terms) for the USA and Japan, which have relatively ambitious NDCs but their policies are lagging behind. For countries with relatively less ambitious NDCs, like China, India, and Russia, the implementation gap is smaller or non-existent, as existing policies overachieve NDC targets in several cases. In the EU, the implementation gap is relatively small due to ambitious policies. The long-term ratchet gap is significant for all cases, meaning that, with current NDC targets, all six countries require a significant boost in post-2030 climate action for their net-zero targets to be achievable. However, differences between models are non-negligible, as GCAM results show an implementation gap in all countries except Russia, while GEMINI results show an implementation gap only for the USA. Driven largely by announced emissions targets, pathways towards long-term targets are relatively similar between the models, except India and Russia, due to different modelled or assumed contributions from non-CO2 emissions and natural sinks towards net-zero targets. We have not assessed the ambition gap at the country level, as that would require an assessment of fairness and equity42.
Scenario Feasibility
The feasibility of the modelled scenarios based on national policies and targets is measured by comparing specific scenario outcomes with pre-determined thresholds. Surpassing a threshold indicates that the feasibility of achievement in that dimension might become concerning. The global results show that feasibility concerns vary strongly between models, between scenarios, and over the different time periods (Fig. 3a). Logically, deeper mitigation efforts imply larger feasibility concerns, as they drive models further away from their emissions-unconstrained baselines. Achieving stated long-term targets among all countries, which is the only option of keeping temperature increase well-below-2°C (Fig. 2), implies that regional feasibility thresholds must be passed three to six times (global weighted average and with median thresholds), depending on the model and aggregated over the different feasibility dimensions. The feasibility metrics are only based on mitigation, and do not consider the adaptation challenges that are driven by a lack of mitigation. In fact, the feasibility of adequate adaptation to make up for a lack of mitigation may be significantly more concerning—i.e. in terms of costs, pace of investment scale-up, and land and freshwater availability43,44—but this is outside the scope of this study. These feasibility concerns can therefore best be understood as key aspects that require attention for successful implementation of the ambitious mitigation policies.
Since the different models significantly differ in structure resulting in a wide variety of mitigation pathways, feasibility concerns also differ between the models (Table 1), with GEMINI showing the lowest and MUSE the highest concerns. However, the distribution of feasibility concerns over the different feasibility dimensions and over time are crucial for the interpretation. For example, the high overall concern for MUSE is largely driven by high carbon prices and demand reduction pathways. In contrast, these dimensions are hardly of concern for GCAM and TIAM, where the pace of technology deployment and—in the case of GCAM—reliance on bioenergy and CCS are the main sources of feasibility concern. When evaluating feasibility concerns over time, all three scenarios from TIAM stand out for showing most concerns in the near term (2030), predominantly related to the high pace of wind and solar energy deployment to deliver on 2030 targets. In GCAM, feasibility concerns are relatively small in the run-up to 2030, but arise in later periods, largely driven by an increasing reliance on bioenergy with carbon capture and storage (BECCS). The latter is concerning from three different feasibility perspectives: the pace of technology deployment, the availability of sustainable bioenergy resources, and geological carbon storage capacity.
Since mitigation scenarios in this study are entirely driven by country-specific climate policies and ambitions, we also specify an overview of measured feasibility concerns for the six largest emitters, averaged over the 2020–2050 period (Fig. 4). While again large differences between models exist, overall, we see relatively low concerns in China and Russia, and high concerns in the USA, the EU, and Japan. These differences are likely driven by more ambitious near- and long-term targets in the latter group, which—despite being already in an emission reduction phase for at least a decade—still confront high feasibility constraints to meet their near- and longer-term targets. Specific feasibility issues that stand out include energy demand reductions in the USA (GEMINI), carbon pricing in the EU (MUSE), and bioenergy and carbon storage potentials for Japan (GCAM). Feasibility concerns about the pace of technology deployment play a relatively small role in China, the USA, and the EU, but a significant role in India, Russia, and Japan.
The interpretation of the measured feasibility concerns can be subjective. The pre-determined thresholds are not set in stone, and often large ranges for such thresholds exist in literature37,38, while threshold levels strongly affect measured feasibility concerns (Fig. 3b). Experts in different fields may have very different views on what is feasible or not. Also, country-specific features, such as the country size, stage of development, and economic structure, as well as access to international financial markets, will influence the threshold level. While some of these features are weighted in the feasibility assessment (e.g., the thresholds for carbon pricing depend on GDP per capita levels), not all country-specific features can be taken into account (e.g., economic structure). Also, some historical cases prove that the chosen thresholds can be overcome. An example is the surge of gas-fired power in the Netherlands and nuclear power in France, which respectively surged from 5–80% and 25–75% of the power mix in one decade, surpassing the applied feasibility threshold in this study over 10-fold. Since such historical examples of fast transitions are typically driven by public policy and support45, the feasibility analysis can also be interpreted as a mapping exercise of where policy support is strongly needed to overcome existing constraints, which is crucial for achieving stated climate targets as all models and scenarios analysed in this study surpass several feasibility thresholds. Nevertheless, as the results show, this mapping strongly depends on the applied model: deep structural differences between models lead to a wide variety of pathways reaching the same climate targets and, hence, different policy interventions are necessary from different modelling perspectives to make these pathways feasible.