Is carbon offsetting a credible way of compensating for emissions from fossil fuels? While firms, investors, governments, non-state actors, and academics alike have wrestled with how to approach carbon offsetting for nearly two decades, this specific question is rarely satisfactorily answered. Before the COVID-19 pandemic induced a temporary dip in global emissions, a new offset boom was underway, characterised by increasing purchase volumes1,2 and interest in niche carbon removal techniques3,4. Organisations are increasingly committing to achieve net zero emissions of carbon dioxide (CO2) before mid-century or as early as 20305. Many of these entities depend on continued use of fossil fuels for activities such as international travel. At present, their only available options are to cease these activities entirely6 or attempt to neutralise their impact with carbon offsetting. The bulk of offsetting options available today are through nature-based climate solutions, whether emission reductions through avoided damage to ecosystems or carbon removal through forestation and other nature-based sequestration. Both of these options will no longer be available to offset fossil fuel emissions in a few decades’ time. In a net-zero world, there is no scope for large-scale offsetting of emissions by paying for emission reductions because those reductions will already have occurred; and the impact of global warming itself is likely to substantially weaken, if not reverse, the strength of the biospheric carbon sink. Hence for continued offsetting of fossil fuel emissions to be compatible with a sustainable transition to net zero emissions, an increasing fraction of the carbon that underpins those offsets must be allocated to very long-term, geological-timescale, storage options7. We propose that this principle can be neatly packaged into a new offsetting instrument, termed a progressive offset or ‘proset’, generating demand for effectively permanent CO2 storage at an affordable cost while not undermining the strong case for immediate investment in shorter-term storage, much of which relies on critically needed nature-based climate solutions.
Offsetting is the act of paying a third party to compensate for the impact of one’s own emissions through one of two actions: emission reduction or carbon removal. Emission reductions denote cases when the third party emits less CO2 relative to a counterfactual baseline (what they would have emitted in the absence of the offset contract). Carbon removals denote cases when CO2 is recovered directly from the atmosphere and stored. In many cases, the emission reduction or carbon removal involves storing the avoided or removed CO2, often in wild or managed ecosystems (forests, soil, etc.) or less commonly in geological formations (saline aquifers, disused oil and gas wells, etc.).
There are many challenges with ensuring the integrity of carbon offsets, documented in offsetting guides8, case studies9, and systematic reviews10. Key concerns affecting integrity include quantification (How much CO2 is actually avoided or taken up?), additionality (Might mitigation have taken place without the offsetting project? Has deforestation simply been displaced?) and permanence (Will a forest remain intact in perpetuity in the face of pests, fire, logging, agricultural development, and global warming itself? Does the offset delay rather than permanently avoid emissions? What is the risk that stored CO2 will be re-emitted to the atmosphere, and if so, how soon?). While all such criteria must be rigorously vetted to ensure integrity, we are chiefly concerned with the question of permanence. CO2 released by fossil fuel combustion elevates global temperatures for hundreds of thousands of years, so to be fully effective, any compensatory storage must, in effect, be equally permanent. Effective permanence can be accomplished either directly by employing CO2 storage techniques very low risks of reversal (e.g. chemical immobilisation of CO2 in basalt formations), or through financial mechanisms that insure any leakage event is remediated by “topping up” a comparable carbon sink. In this way, higher-risk storage techniques could be made “permanent”, provided trust is maintained in the institutions and legal instruments used to ensure liability for remediating leaks.
Beyond offset quality criteria, there are two further overarching challenges that threaten to undermine the effectiveness of voluntary carbon offsetting. The first is the risk of overly-relying on emission reductions over carbon removals. Most currently-available carbon offsets come from emission reduction projects which, even if perfectly administered, are not sustainable in a net zero world. Once global emissions reach net zero, there will be no scope to compensate for ongoing emissions by paying a third party to reduce their emissions. Use of emission reductions must therefore be transitory and ultimately give way to exclusive reliance on removals.
Proset definition: A proset is a financial instrument that allows the purchaser to compensate for the impact of CO2 emissions from fossil fuel use by committing an equivalent quantity of CO2 to a combination of permanent and sub-permanent storage, with the fraction stored permanently increasing progressively over time following a path that is defined by the proset itself and consistent with 100% permanent storage by a specified target date. “Permanent” denotes storage that is expected to persist for longer than the 10,000-year timescales associated with geological storage, while sub-permanent denotes 100 years or greater, associated with the most secure storage options in the biosphere and oceans and with conventional storage time horizon expectations in offsetting markets.
|
Second, it is not possible to compensate indefinitely for continued use of fossil fuels through carbon removal with Nature-based Climate Solutions (NbCS, meaning the management of natural or human-mediated biological systems such as forests, grasslands, wetlands, and increasingly agricultural soils to enhance carbon storage). Large scale conversion of fossil carbon into biologically-stored carbon is inherently unsustainable because the global biosphere’s capacity may be quite limited11. Projections of the rate of release of carbon from the biosphere by mid-century, for example through thawing tundra or increased wildfires, are similar to optimistic estimates of the potential global rate of carbon uptake by NbCS12. It is therefore possible that all available NbCS options will be required simply to prevent the global biosphere from further exacerbating global warming, leaving no additional capacity to compensate for ongoing fossil fuel emissions. Users of NbCS to compensate for fossil fuel emissions need to recognise that they are tapping into a rapidly depleting global resource which is under fierce competition from other land uses, primarily agriculture and timber management to provide food and fibre.
Despite these challenges, the global market for voluntary offsetts approached 100 million metric tonnes of carbon-dioxide equivalent (MtCO2e) in 2018 at an average price of around $3 per tonne13. This highlights a further problem with the offset market as currently constituted: offset prices are typically too low to motivate buyers to reduce their own emissions, locking in high-carbon behaviour and investment.
Growing awareness of these problems with traditional offsetting has fuelled interest in specialised products that compensate for the impact of fossil fuel emissions by direct air capture of CO2 and permanent geological sequestration (DACCS) or remineralisation (converting CO2 into rock). These are currently much more expensive than traditional offsets (e.g. $775/tCO2 for DACCS3). An intermediate option, conventional carbon capture and storage, provides comparably-permanent storage at a cost that is an order of magnitude cheaper, bit faces challenges of public acceptability and is therefore less readily adaptable to generating voluntary carbon offsets.
In summary, any entity aiming to neutralise the impact of its fossil fuel emissions in the next few years is faced with an uncomfortable choice between 1) cheap but very possibly ineffective traditional carbon credits, 2) moderately more expensive but as-yet commercially unavailable conventional carbon capture and storage, and 3) unreproachable but extremely expensive and scarce DACCS.